My topic has evolved over time.
Originally, I planned to pick up where Paul Champlin had left off on the
subject of taxes in the Civil War. But I then decided to broaden things
by talking about financing the war in general, but at the same time focusing
primarily on this crop of cotton and how it affected both sides. That
focus caused me to get into the whole issue of trading with the enemy. And
along the way, I delved into various tangential topics that I found
interesting. So if tonight’s talk seems like a hodgepodge that is because
of my research journey.
Abraham Lincoln in his first inaugural address
said that, “Physically speaking, we cannot separate.” And that proved
prophetic because as much as the South tried to forge a new country, it just
wasn’t possible due to existing economic bonds. Late in the war, for
example, Jefferson Davis became particularly incensed over the wide circulation
of greenbacks within the Confederacy itself. And remember that greenbacks
were something entirely new, even in the North. And so the preference of
people in Confederate-controlled areas to use them, despite laws prohibiting
such circulation, says a lot about how viable Southern nationhood ultimately
was.
I want to start out on the Southern side with
an incident early in the war. We all know that much second-guessing or
Monday-morning quarterbacking occurred over military affairs during the war,
with probably the most controversy being over Longstreet and Pickett’s Charge,
but there was also an ongoing fiscal dispute as well.
At the very beginning of the Confederacy in
1861, Judah P. Benjamin [SLIDE], the jack-of-all-trades in Jeff Davis’s
cabinet, suggested that all the cotton that could be laid hands on should be
shipped to Europe posthaste for safekeeping, either in Britain or France.
And then as needs arose, the cotton, being reasonably imperishable, could be
sold off to obtain necessary supplies. Much of the cabinet objected to
this plan, with then-Secretary of the Treasury, Christopher Gustavus Memminger
[SLIDE], being most prominent in opposition. He found the proposal
unconstitutional and economically unwise.
So they didn’t do it. After the war, Jeff
Davis [SLIDE], mouldering away in prison, complained that if only we hadn’t
listened to that darn Memminger, we would have won the war. The Yankees
wouldn’t have strangled us with their blockade [SLIDE], and the South would
have gained its independence. Also, former General Joseph E. Johnston, no
friend of Davis’s, agreed, writing in his memoirs, that the Confederacy
collapsed not because of military weakness, but of financial. So again,
we have another one of those “what if” questions we often run into in
history.
Now does anyone find anything disingenuous or
even downright bogus about the complaints of Davis and Johnston as to this
supposed lost opportunity? Let me give you a hint: Embargo.
Benjamin’s plan really never had a chance because everyone, including Davis,
was embargo-crazy. This was the application of King Cotton diplomacy
[SLIDE], the idea that Europe could not survive without Southern cotton.
In 1861, then, the approach was to withhold cotton from Europe, causing wide-spread
economic disruption and thereby leading to recognition from the European powers
and possibly even military assistance. And that was even a grass-roots
movement at the time, whereby local vigilance committees were set up at ports
to make sure no cotton left the South, burning it if need be.
The embargo did not work, primarily because
Europe actually had a glut of cotton at the time due to bumper crops in
1857-1860 and was even exploring alternative sources of supply in Egypt and
India. And historians often point to this as example of folly and note
how it actually only served the purposes of the Union as the blockade was not
yet operational. Only when it was starting to become reasonably
effective, the South realized their embargo strategy was not working and so
they would have to start exporting.
At this point, I want to take a moment to
question the conventional wisdom about the embargo strategy by saying that just
because something doesn’t work, doesn’t mean it’s stupid. And I bring
this up because in my research, I found that as the war dragged on, both
Britain and France suffered terrible economic devastation due to the lack of
cotton. I know we like to remember how the unselfish workingmen of
Manchester wrote to Lincoln after the Emancipation Proclamation to support the
Union’s cause. And there’s even a statue of Lincoln in Manchester today,
but still the suffering caused cannot be glossed over. And in France,
with its own significant textile industry, the government was particularly
worried as there were still people alive who could recall the Reign of Terror,
as well as subsequent episodes of social unrest. You all saw Les
Miserables, right?
And there have even been suggestions that
Lincoln preferred that the blockade be somewhat “leaky,” so that Europe was not
too starved of cotton just for these reasons of global stability. In
other words, this was a “safety valve” to let off some pressure.
So what I’m getting at is that maybe Jeff
Davis and company were not entirely nuts in pushing the embargo; they do not
necessarily deserve to be the subjects of ridicule that they have been for all
these years. Embargoes can be quite effective. I think most people
in this room might remember a little matter in 1973 when we were subject to an
embargo, and that ended up leading to the largest transfer of wealth in human
history. So give OPEC credit for that. But in the end, we find that
Davis did not count on that initial glut of cotton in Europe, and he also
didn’t expect the British and French elites to arrive at the calculation that
they did in balancing domestic unrest with antagonizing the Union. So
ultimately, Davis gambled and lost.
Also, I want to take a little swipe at Judah
Benjamin’s plan. He wanted to store all this cotton overseas, and as I understand
it, cotton can be stored for relatively long periods of time, although I could
never determine if there was a true expiration date for raw cotton. But
would this cotton be just as safe as money in a Swiss bank account used to
be? Possibly not. After all, what would prevent Britain and France
from just one day renouncing their declarations of neutrality and then seizing
the cotton either on behalf of their now-Yankee allies or in their own national
interests? After all, Russian assets had been seized during the Crimean
War. As Davis later said, “Put not your trust in princes.”
Also, I need to mention that in a recent post
in the New York Times’s Disunion blog, Professor Terry Jones of the University
of Louisiana threw cold water on this argument by noting that while the South
certainly suffered privations during the war, it has never been documented that
it lost a battle for lack of armaments. Rather, it was at a natural
disadvantage for want of men and an efficient railroad system.
But let’s go off on one of my tangents, and
talk about Secretary Memminger a little more [SLIDE]. This is him on $5
Confederate bill. He’s not often mentioned as a leading light of the
Davis cabinet, but he’s intriguing nonetheless. While both Memminger and
Benjamin were lawyers and both were foreign-born, the resemblance pretty much
ends there. Judah Benjamin was an outsized personality, but Memminger was
apparently something of a nerd. Born in Germany, he was brought to
Charleston, South Carolina as an infant by his widowed mother who herself died
shortly after their arrival, leaving him to grow up in an orphanage, and so
despite all his later successes, he was always known as a foundling.
Luckily, he was essentially adopted by one of the trustees of the orphanage,
and even entered the University of South Carolina at age 11, graduating at age
14, so he must have been quite the prodigy. Also at that time, South
Carolina maybe wasn‘t the party school it is now.
He began practicing law, concentrating in
business matters. He first made his mark with the so-called Bank
Case. He represented the State of South Carolina suing certain banks that
had suspended specie payments in the aftermath of the Panic of 1837. When
I say “specie,” I mean gold and silver. The State sought to have the
charters of these banks revoked. Memminger ended up winning, and by doing
so, he helped to actually burnish the reputation of the banks in South Carolina
for exceptional soundness. And he himself, became known as a “Sound
Money” man, which we will shortly learn came to be way ironic.
At the start of the war, Memminger was
appointed Treasury Secretary not so much for his business background but as
part of the dust settling over how to have the cabinet represent all the
seceded states, while also allowing Jeff Davis to settle old scores with his
enemies.
Once in office, Memminger was suspect as he
was not a true aristocrat but a foundling. Further, he was seen as
foreign, often being referred to as “the Hessian,” even though I found no
indication that he could actually even speak German since he immigrated as an
infant, much less that he spoke English with other than a South Carolinian
accent.
But Memminger had as much business background
as anyone else that Davis could have appointed, and he soon put that to good
use in arranging loans for the newborn Confederacy. And that was the
traditional means of financing American wars. That is how U.S. Treasury
Secretary Chase initially wanted to do it. But it was especially
difficult for the South as it had always depended on the North for the
infrastructure of finance. You might recall how Thomas Jefferson abhorred
the “paper-men” and stock jobbers of Wall Street. All the bank notes and
bonds had been engraved in New York. They didn’t even have the right
paper.
In any event, Memminger was able to
arrange a number of loans, probably the most successful was in May, 1861, which
he obtained from individual Southern citizens in the approximate amount of $15
million in gold and silver. In a flush of Southern nationalism, a healthy
slug of the specie in private hands in the South was acquired by the
Confederate treasury. These loans, known collectively as the “Specie
Loan,” were for 10 years’ duration with 8% interest payments payable in gold
from the export tax on cotton that was also payable only in gold. (If
you’re a fancier of Confederate money, you know that that disclaimer is printed
on every bill [SLIDE].) Further, the Confederacy seized about $5 million
in gold from Federal customhouses and mints. They start out, then, in
that first year of the war with about $20 million in specie. So Memminger
sets out to honor his sound money background.
So what did they do with that initial $20
million? Soon most of it was promptly on its way to Europe to acquire
needed war supplies. This is how the Alabama and other commerce raiders
were paid for. That’s how the European suppliers were paid. How did
the Confederate soldiers and civil servants get paid? Well, Memminger now
had to rapidly change his spots and crank up that old printing press and churn
out more examples of what I showed you earlier [SLIDE]. (This is of
course Lincoln printing money, but likely there were similar cartoons of Davis
and Memminger in Southern newspapers.) And this matter of fiat currency
is easily a whole college course, but for our purposes, if you print too much,
it’s not good.
And as we know, this is not ancient
history. We still have questions of reliability and soundness. You
might recall a few years ago when we were facing the fiscal cliff, and some
suggested that President Obama simply mint a trillion dollar coin. Many
dismissed the idea at the time as hare-brained, but was that really any different
than a lot of expedients that Governments resort to over time. Would it
have been much different than those giant stone coins you’ve seen in National
Geographic on the Yap Islands in the south Pacific. If people put faith
in them, they are worth something. But as I suggested earlier, this was
so awful for Memminger, Mr. Sound Money, in that he had to preside over this
sorry spectacle.
And on another tangent, I want to address a
common view: Often it is suggested that because there was so much
counterfeit Confederate money the Southern economy collapsed. Without
doubt, there was a lot of counterfeit Confederate money circulating, much of it
printed in the North. And Memminger himself even accused the Union
Government of being behind this effort. But at the end of the day, the
Confederates did not need much help in destroying their own economy. The
South was so awash in these shinplasters rolling off the official printing
presses that it’s hard to believe the counterfeit bills made much difference.
And don’t forget the states of the Confederacy printed money too, as well as
the Indian Territory and Confederate-occupied Arizona [SLIDE]. Now
interestingly, much scholarly study has been devoted to the Confederate
economy, but the highest estimate I have found is that 2.5% of the money supply
in the South was counterfeit. And remember that’s what the economists
call M0, the base money supply. We have to assume that after the first
few years, so many transactions were through barter. If you read that
wonderful novel “Cold Mountain,” you recall all the trading going on just to
survive.
Back to Memminger, he was not a man of
imagination. But in a few years, on his watch at least, and this is also
wildly ironic, a remarkable financial device comes into being, one that is
still discussed today in financial studies. In late 1862, Europe was
getting squeezed with an increasing cotton famine, the earlier glut having been
worked through and with Egypt and India apparently unable to make up the
shortfall. And I have read in some sources that the quality of cotton
from those other countries was not up to the standard of Southern cotton.
Buy American. At this point, an enterprising French financier named Emil
Erlanger comes on the scene [SLIDE]. He proposes to the Confederacy that
his family’s bank, which rivaled Rothschild in prominence, would underwrite a
bond offering to the tune of $15 million. Each bond would be denominated
in pounds sterling or French francs. It was to pay out an annual rate of
interest of 7%, which was not bad then and is great now. And payment was
to be in either pounds or francs, not Confederate money.
But that’s not all. Unlike conventional
bonds, which typically rely on the confidence residing in the issuing party,
these bonds had a conversion feature. At any time, you could surrender
your bond for a set amount of cotton, typically 20,000 pounds, at the set price
of the equivalent of 12 cents a pound, regardless of the prevailing market
price, which at the time could be as high as a dollar a pound. So this is
the famous Erlanger Cotton Bond [SLIDE].
Now to this day, finance scholars and economic
historians write about this device as it was so innovative. You see it is
more than a common debt instrument. It has the quality of a derivative as
we would call it today. Its value derives from an underlying commodity,
here the cotton. And more specifically, we would say it’s a call option,
that is, the holder can decide to “call” on the counterparty to deliver the
goods, so the holder can exercise the option at a time of his choosing or
not. The need was to entice investors by allowing them flexibility, so
that they’d take the risk [SLIDE]. Notice this detail of Liberty leaning
on bales of cotton.
But there was a catch: The Confederates
would deliver up the cotton, but they would only deliver it up inside the
Confederacy. The bond’s issuer was only obligated to deliver the cotton
to a point “within ten miles of a navigable river or railhead,” and then you
had to arrange your own transportation. Wouldn’t that be a little like
have to obtain a shipment today inside Syria? But the Erlanger folks
being a full-service firm had a solution for their clients. They had
their own blockade-runner [SLIDE] called the Denbigh, named after a town in
Wales, and for an additional fee, they would get it out of the Confederacy and
to Havana. And their ship made 13 round trips between Mobile or Galveston
and Havana before the war ended. If you didn’t want to pay the fee, then
you had to just content yourself with the coupon payments and hope the South
wins. But for the South, that was a good thing as these investors had a
stake in the Confederacy.
When they were first issued in early 1863,
they were quite popular, even Chancellor of the Exchequer William Gladstone
bought some. Union diplomats soon started a whisper campaign, oddly
enough not about the vulnerability of the South, but about how Jefferson
Davis as a U.S. Senator had supported Mississippi’s action in defaulting on
bonds held primarily by European investors. The Confederates for their
part, tried to buttress the bonds by suggesting that even if the South lost the
war, the U.S. Government would honor the obligations under the bonds.
This was probably not completely an insane idea. After all, Alexander
Hamilton set something of a precedent when he convinced the Federal Government
to assume the Revolutionary War debts of the states, and thereby creating our
National Debt, when that was considered a good thing.
But of course, honoring the debts of an enemy
is different from honoring the debts of a constituent part of yourself.
And after the war, with this situation in mind, one provision of the 14th
Amendment explicitly provides that any debt incurred in aid of insurrection or
rebellion is illegal and void. So deal with that, Gladstone. I hope
you diversified [SLIDE].
Now the trading value of the bonds obviously
fluctuated with the fortunes of the Confederacy. Not long after issuance,
they buoyed with the Union defeat at Chancellorsville, and then sagged after
Gettysburg. They edged up again in the summer of 1864 with war-weariness
in the North and the possibility of a McClellan election victory on a peace plank,
but then Sherman stepped in. Ultimately, the Confederacy obtained about
$8.5 million from the bonds, but then it is hard to know exactly how much was
offset by the cotton that was redeemed. Generally, however, most
observers think it ended up being a pretty good deal for all concerned, all
things considered. Undoubtedly, many investors lost out and only saw
three coupon interest payments before the Confederacy collapsed, but is that
much different from many business opportunities today? High risk, high
reward and all that. The South did get much-needed foreign exchange and
some investors got a dandy deal on cotton.
One final footnote, it is sometimes suggested
that the only reason the Cotton Bonds were floated was because Emile Erlanger
was simultaneously romancing Marguerite Slidell, the daughter of the James
Slidell, of the Trent Affair and the Confederate envoy to Napoleon III.
I’m not sure how much that had to do with it, but the two did end up
marrying. She gained some kind of noble title, and he did philanthropic
work in the South after the war, even establishing a hospital in Chattanooga,
which is still there today. It is a prestigious teaching hospital
associated with the University of Tennessee. And there’s a town in Kentucky
named Erlanger due to his beneficence.
So the South initially tried to weaponize
cotton in a way, but later saw the need to monetize it. In contrast, the
Union needed cotton as a raw material, as well as to keep the South from using
it for barter. As the Union Army moved South, early on, the need was seen
for Treasury agents or buyers authorized by the Treasury to obtain
cotton. Ideally, the Army would seize cotton from disloyal growers under
one of the confiscation acts. But when seizure wasn’t possible, you had
to haggle, and that brought on the ongoing debate of how to pay.
Different methods were thought up at different
times. Earlier in the war, one arrangement was to make an immediate
payment 2/3 payment in greenbacks [SLIDE], with the remaining 1/3 payment in
U.S. Government bonds to be held in escrow in a Union-controlled bank until
hostilities ended and the seller had maintained loyalty to the Union throughout
the intervening period. So that was a fairly stiff condition subsequent
to the deal. But from the Union standpoint, this was desirable as it
would mean these growers had a definite economic stake in a Union victory,
something like those European investors who bought the cotton bonds betting on
a Confederate victory.
Later in the war, in January 1864, the
Treasury issued rules whereby sellers had to take a loyalty oath to the Union
under Lincoln’s December 1863 amnesty proclamation, and then you would get 25%
of the price in greenbacks, with a receipt for the rest to be cashed after the
war, assuming the holder had been loyal throughout. So the Union was
improving its own terms of payment with the growers getting less up
front.
That was the ideal, but the reality was that
either unlicensed traders or corrupt licensed traders or even Government employees,
both military and civilian, would pay in gold, that is, in specie. Like
Memminger, these were “sound money” men. Sometimes this practice was
winked at, even at the highest levels. It was certainly not popular with
folks like Grant and Sherman as it appeared to be downright treason, aid and
comfort to the enemy and all that. General E.R.S. Canby [SLIDE] wrote to
Lincoln complaining how the Government’s policies hampered the military effort
because cotton traders would tip off the Confederates of pending invasions to
prevent them from burning cotton. But Lincoln, was a little more
pragmatic, or a little more shrewd. Lincoln explained that since the
price of cotton had jumped six times since the war started and since the enemy
usually ran the blockade with one-sixth the amount exported in peacetime, he
was getting the same deal without planting the other five crops and raising
provisions instead. And it was better to give him guns for his cotton,
than let him get it to Europe where he’d get guns and ammunition. So
Lincoln was betting that he could outlast the South even when giving them
aid. And he made the calculation that it was worth it. I can just
imagine if Grant or Sherman read this letter.
Now with that as economic background, we have
the tale of three cities: Memphis, Tennessee, Helena, Arkansas, and New
Orleans, Louisiana. By the summer of 1862, all three of these Mississippi
River ports had been taken.
The occupation of Memphis was eagerly awaited
by Northern merchants seeking to open it for trade. Sherman [SLIDE] was
initially put in charge and he had no truck with inter-belligerent trade,
particularly banning the use of gold to buy cotton. But he was forced to
back down by Secretary of War Stanton. Even though Stanton certainly
agreed in principle with Sherman, Secretary of State Seward had pressured him
to try and help relieve the cotton shortage in Europe as a foreign policy
matter. Due to the vibrancy of trade through Memphis, both licit and
Illicit, Sherman complained that Cincinnati ended up providing more supplies to
the Confederacy than Charleston, South Carolina, a chief entrepôt for
blockade-runners.
Another busy river town was Helena, Arkansas,
which was overseen by General Samuel Curtis [SLIDE], a West Pointer and also
one of the first Republicans elected to Congress. Further, despite being
outnumbered, he was the victor of the Battle of Pea Ridge, an important fight
in the Western Theater. Unfortunately, his stewardship of Helena did not
leave him similarly cloaked in glory. Less than three months after taking
control, he reportedly deposited $100,000 with a Chicago financier. And
it was alleged that Curtis only occupied Helena, rather than the state capital
at Little Rock, because that was where the cotton was. Despite denials of
impropriety, he was soon transferred out of Helena, although the apparent
corruption continued there among the lower ranks.
And now we come to the star of our show, old
Beast Butler[SLIDE], and his stage, the Crescent City. Now assigning
Butler to New Orleans is a little like carrying coals to Newcastle as the place
was not previously a model of rectitude and civic integrity. But Butler,
along with his conniving brother, Andrew Jackson Butler, quickly got to work in
the filthy lucre department. For some perspective, when Butler arrived in
New Orleans in May 1862, he had a personal wealth of $150,000. Six years
later, he was worth about $3 million.
What were his specific methods? Soon
after assuming occupation duties, he promised any planter who brought cotton
into his lines would not see it confiscated, even if it was actually owned by a
high Confederate official. That was clearly against stated Union policy,
and so it must have otherwise been worth his while to proclaim such a
policy. Further, he arranged with the Confederate commander of Mobile to
establish a regular exchange of cotton for salt. Salt, of course, was
essential to food preservation in those days. And this intercourse was
apparently of quite some volume.
Well, soon enough, however, New Orleans got a
new sheriff. This man [SLIDE] Nathaniel Banks was directed to assume
command in December 1862. Banks was a prominent politician in his home
state of Massachusetts, and, interestingly, had started his working life as a
“bobbin boy” in a textile mill, so this matter of cotton was somewhat in his
blood. It was hoped that Banks could undo the culture of corruption
overseen by Butler and his brother, and it was hoped that Banks could use New
Orleans as a jumping off point for more aggressive campaigning. You see
when New Orleans was first captured, many hoped that the city would serve as a
conduit for cotton to pass on its way to the New England mills. But
despite all Butler’s innovative approaches, such as his salt trading schemes,
and Banks’s later clean-up efforts, New Orleans turned out to be a
disappointment as an export center; not that much cotton was coming through.
One problem was that many of the plantation
slaves in the area under Union control had fled, meaning cotton couldn’t be
harvested. Banks dealt with this situation as had other Union commanders,
such as on the South Carolina coast, by setting up a system that essentially
ordered the slaves back to work. Even though occupied Louisiana was exempt
under the Emancipation Proclamation, Banks decreed that they were to be paid,
somewhat fairly, but they were still also to be subservient to the
planters. And while Banks explained that he hoped to rely mostly on moral
suasion to get the workers back on the plantations, everyone understood that
the Union Army would make them if they didn’t. Presumably, if they didn’t
return to work, they’d be arrested for loitering or vagrancy, with the
punishment being the work farm. You see how the seeds are planted for the
later Jim Crow system. But even with this approach, the appetite of the
North and of Europe for cotton remained great.
As a result, an old dream revived, that of
invading and occupying Texas. Now the idea of Yankees getting into Texas
actually pre-dated the war. Edward Everett Hale, the author of “The Man
Without a Country,” had long suggested that Northerners settle in Texas, a
concept akin to what the New England Emigrant Aid Company was doing in Kansas
before the war. The idea was later propagated more broadly by this man
[SLIDE] Edward Atkinson, a life-long agitator, who coincidentally was also a
mill owner in New England. He published a brochure entitled “Cheap Cotton
by Free Labor” promoting the idea. He argued that cotton could be grown
more efficiently by free workers, and as support, he pointed to the existing
German population in Texas that was growing cotton without slaves. In his
accounting, free labor would be three times more productive raising cotton than
slave labor, and this example would force the rest of the South to abandon
slavery. That was the dream.
Once the war began, Atkinson and his like-minded
fellows became even more aggressive in pushing their ideas, along with a number
of prominent Texan refugees now camped out at the Willard Hotel in
Washington. And they even raised the stakes and recommended not just an
armed invasion and occupation of Texas, but also that land should be
confiscated from disloyal owners and awarded to troops in the invasion force as
a kind of bounty.
Back to Atkinson for a moment, in the wake of
the Spanish-American War, he became one of the founders of the Anti-Imperialist
League, which objected to our annexation of the Philippines and Hawaii.
But it is okay to colonize Texas.
And one more tangent if I may, a similar
proposal was made regarding Florida. And in fact, if you recall the novel
The Yearling, later made into the movie with Gregory Peck, which was set in
Florida, and one of the characters was a Yankee settler, not a carpetbagger,
but someone who put down roots. So if you think the first Northerners to
come to Florida were Jerry Seinfeld’s parents, you would be wrong.
Now obviously, a big part of why they wanted
to invade Texas was for the cotton, so you have this Texas-New England axis
going, but also many, such as McClellan, thought it would be good to succor
pro-Union parties in Texas, especially those Germans we were talking
about. You might have seen this gruesome lithograph of a mass hanging of
suspected Unionists. [SLIDE.] And of course, in 1862 with the
arrival of the French in Mexico [SLIDE], a proposed campaign into Texas assumes
a foreign policy dimension as it would signal that the U.S. is not completely
distracted by its internal wrangling, but also, as many suggested, it may ward
off the French from themselves trying to occupy Texas.
Okay, so great idea. Let’s do it.
And originally, the grand scheme had been for a two-pronged approach, with one
army invading Texas for all the above-mentioned reasons and another army
taking New Orleans as a preliminary to opening the Mississippi.
Well, there is a problem with manpower.
Remember the Eastern Theater too. You just don’t have enough men.
And politics intervenes as Midwestern governors urge the opening of the
Mississippi as critical to their local economies, and since the Republicans had
taken a “shellacking” in these same states in the 1862 fall elections, they
have Lincoln’s ear, and that becomes the priority. Also, things just
generally get bogged down in New Orleans, with Banks having to set up shop and
try and clean up after Butler’s mess.
Also another assignment that hampered Banks in
plans to invade Texas was that Lincoln expected him to make Louisiana viable as
a reconstructed state. During the war itself, Lincoln and Congress had a
tug-of-war over reconstruction policies, which is itself a discrete topic that
could occupy an evening. Briefly stated, to the Lincoln Administration,
the rebel states had not truly left the Union, it was just that some traitors
had temporarily assumed control, and so the President, under his authority to
suppress insurrections, could determine how they were restored. To the
Congress, the rebel states would be conquered territory, as if they’d been
taken from the Indians or from Mexico, and so Congress had the authority to set
the terms of admission. Suffice it to say that Lincoln wanted Banks to
serve as a kind of Roman Procounsul, and sort out the local politics so that
the state would count for purposes of the 10% of the population swearing
loyalty under his amnesty plan.
But Banks did try a few forays, mostly along
the Texas coast. These ended up being mostly “pinprick” efforts without
much lasting effect. Further, Banks was confounded by vague instructions
from Henry Halleck. He kept “intimating” that Banks may wish to proceed
up the Red River in northwest Louisiana [SLIDE], where the cotton was and that
could also serve as jumping off point for Texas, but he was never all that
clear in expressing himself. Now the problem of Civil War generals
writing inadequate orders is hardly an isolated problem, and we even find
research from World War II about how communication between Eisenhower and his
subordinates was not always crystal clear. In any event, Banks eventually
got organized and moved up the Red River, along with the Navy under Admiral
David Porter [SLIDE].
I’m not here to provide a campaign
narrative. I’ll just say what many of you probably already know, and that
is that the Red River Campaign was a failure. I’m not sure you could call
it an utter disaster, but it certainly wasn’t what many had hoped for.
And many historians believe that it actually ended up lengthening the war
due to the diversion of resources that could have been better applied
elsewhere. I think the most distinct image of failure from the campaign
was how they had to retreat back to New Orleans more quickly out of fear that
many of the Navy’s ships would be stranded when the river’s level dropped in
the spring. Also memorable was Banks’s senior officers seriously
considered putting him under arrest. And it wasn’t unalloyed glory for
the Confederates either as you had Edmund Kirby Smith [SLIDE], of the
Trans-Mississippi Department or Kirby-Smithdom, feuding with General Richard
Taylor, the irritable son of the former President.
For our economic purposes, the Red River
campaign was a shameful matter as you have the Army and Navy competing against
each other to obtain the most cotton. You have the Navy under Admiral
Porter, becoming quite inventive in seizing cotton under the maritime prize
system, as was more typically done on the high seas against truly foreign
enemies. But this incentivized the Navy as prize money was doled out
according to rank. The Navy was quite notorious for sending Marines far
inland to seize cotton, even going to the trouble of bringing along engine-room
mechanics to repair damaged gins so they could themselves bale recently
harvested cotton. I’ve never baled cotton, but I’ve baled hay, and I
can’t imagine in those days that it would have been very easy. So that
shows how anxious they were to make a buck out of this valuable commodity.
The Southerners even gave Porter the nom de guerre “Thief of the Mississippi.”
And the action of the Navy caused friction with the soldiers along whom
they were serving. I assume this is the only instance of Army-Navy
friction in our history. But there are indications that the Army also
made out well in this grab for cotton.
After the war, Congress decided to investigate
the Red River campaign to uncover mismanagement and graft. Admiral Porter
testified and not only laid the blame on General Banks of course but also
perjured himself by claiming the Navy never seized cotton for prizes, when he
himself profited handsomely. Generally, the verdict on the campaign was
that it was just a commercial venture to obtain cotton with redeeming military value.
But once again, I feel sorely obliged to play
devil’s advocate and note that just because something fails due to poor
execution does not mean it should not have been done. I’m not sure the
economic goal necessarily taints the exercise. And further, there was the
need to demonstrate some ability to project power in that theater to ward off
the French. Also it would shore up the reconstructed states of
Louisiana and Arkansas. And more concretely, if they had taken Texas,
that would have cut off another vital avenue of cotton export across the Rio
Grande.
[SLIDE] In the end, the South also came
away with a bad taste as to its cotton strategy. I mentioned earlier
Benjamin’s plan to ship cotton to Europe. But also many in the South were
disturbed by the corrupting influence of the trade across the lines. As
one Confederate officer wrote in early 1865, “The fact is that cotton, instead
of contributing to our strength, has been the greatest element of our weakness
here. Yankee gold is fact accomplishing what Yankee arms could never
achieve—the subjugation of this people.”
Much of what I’ve been discussing
tonight has certainly been tawdry. You see the spectacle of the
Northern profiteers, embodied most fulsomely by Spoons Butler, but what
should be seen as even more awful is the example of all the Southern planters,
the planter class, the ones who started the war, the backbone of the rebellion,
blithely selling out. After all, Yankees are supposed to be ruthless and
without honor. But now you have these gallant Southrons more than anxious
to abandon ship.
Now maybe they can’t be blamed too much
because of the geography. In his book “Terrible Swift Sword,” Bruce
Catton wrote, “In any war, the men who die for patriotism die also for the
enrichment of cold-eyed schemers who risk nothing, and every battlefield is
made uglier by the greed of men who never fight. But what was happening
here, although it included all of that, went far beyond it. This was
conclusive evidence that the warring states were tragically and mysteriously
bound together. Fighting to destroy each other, the two nations still had
to have each other’s help.”
In reviewing all the various accounts of
greed, I can’t help thinking of Joseph Heller’s book “Catch-22.” That was
set during World War II, and if you read it or, more likely, saw the movie by
Mike Nichols, you may remember a character named Milo Minderbinder, who began
as a mess officer at a fictional bomber base in Italy but who rose to
prominence as an off-duty entrepreneur who traded in a certain commodity.
Does anyone remember what that commodity was? Exactly, cotton, and
specifically, Egyptian cotton.
And at one point, Minderbinder acquired cotton
with the intent to sell it at a profit when the bottom drops out of the market
and he is stuck. But never fear, being a good capitalist, he arranges to
sell the cotton to the Germans, in a little inter-belligerent trade.
There was only one wrinkle: He had to have the B-29s bomb their own base.
And since everyone on the base effectively worked for him, he was able to have
it done.
Now the book and the movie were
obviously absurdist and exaggerated, which was especially appreciated in those
cynical Vietnam days, but at the same time, Grant and Sherman would have surely
pointed at Butler and others of his ilk as being quite willing to do what
Minderbinder was willing to do, all for the almighty dollar. But then,
Butler and Minderbinder and all those other great entrepreneurs would have come
back and said something like, what is good for GM is good for the
country. And when you read Lincoln’s letter to Canby, the one about the
price going up six times, and the exports going down six times, maybe it is
hard to draw bright lines.
Questions?
Delivered May 20, 2015
No comments:
Post a Comment